When, sometime in the future, historians come
to undertake an historical analysis of the culture of banking in the UK at the
beginning of the 21st Century, the following words may prove to be a prescient
starting point for them.
'You can't impose moral standards on people who
don't wish to be moral':
This statement of the glaringly obvious was
uttered by disgraced former RBS banker, John Cameron in answer to questioning
in front of the Parliamentary Commission on banking standards, and it is on
this issue I wish to focus in this blog.
Cameron was seeking to make a big distinction
in the culture of bankers as opposed to those people employed by the banks to
trade in financial markets. He was saying that although he and his fellow
directors had done everything they could to inculcate an environment of ethical
standards and 'best practice' within the dealing environment, the traders
themselves had proved to be impervious to these attempts and had just ignored
all management efforts and had carried on regardless of Cameron's or anyone
else's pronouncements.
Cameron referred at one stage to the trading misbehavior being so blatant but that 'no-one had seen a need to cover up
their conduct'.
It never seemed to occur to him that it was his
job as a director of the bank, indeed, as the senior director at one point, to
take the necessary steps to take control of this state of affairs, and therein,
lies his own cultural dilemma, and indeed, part of the answer to the problem of
why the financial sector has sunk to its present level of cultural
dysfunctionality.
We can trace it back, I believe, to the changes
in the City of London introduced in the
era of 'Big Bang'. I believe that the transformation of London from a
UK-centric financial market, with international links, into a 24/7 global hub, operating on equal terms
with New York and Tokyo, completely changed our financial culture and turned
us, almost overnight, into a clone of the US market model, but without enabling
us to adapt our traditional methods and
practices to take account of these changes within the same time frame.
Probably the single most important element of
the financial revolution of the late 1970s, was the ultimate abolition of what
was called 'single capacity' dealing. Back in those days pre 1986, the rules of
the Stock Exchange required that the broking and dealing function of share
trading, be split into two, entirely separate, single capacity functions. Those
who were involved in bringing securities to the stock market, the 'jobbers'
acted as principals to the market in the contracts they offered, so they could
name their price, and were regulated by the element of price competition that
each firm of jobbers had with their competing firms. The people who acted for
the individual clients, the 'brokers' had the job to negotiate the best price
for their clients, buying from or selling to the jobbers who dealt in those
specific stocks. The brokers were paid by a fixed commission rate which was
laid down by the Exchange, and no-one could deal below that price. This enabled
the brokers to act completely independently for their clients, secure in the
knowledge that they would get paid a sensible profitable fee rate, whatever
happened, so their income was secured. In this way they were encouraged to put
the interests of their clients first, because they were going to be paid come
whatever.
This system had operated for a few hundred
years and was a well recognised primary function of the London market. However,
it differed radically from the way in which the Americans operated the New York
Stock Exchange and other, smaller regional exchanges.
For some theoretical reason to do with a
political view of competition best practice, a number of influential Labour
politicians and civil servants considered fixed commissions for stockbrokers to
be anti-competitive, and they had taken positive steps to bring pressure on the
Stock Exchange to abolish the fixed commission structure. Roy Hattersley, under
an earlier Labour Government, had referred the Rule Book of the Stock Exchange
to the Office of Fair Trading, for them to consider its competition issues, and
the case was grinding on and on.
Certain very experienced City practitioners
tried to point out that abolishing the single capacity of jobbers and brokers,
would, de facto, spell the end of the traditional role of the Stock Exchange in
the management of the City markets, and undermine the very careful balance of
competing interests which had developed over hundreds of years, being in the
interests of both market practitioners and market users.
I interviewed Sir Peter Tapsell a senior stockbroker and a Conservative
Member of Parliament when I was researching my book on city fraud called
'...Fraud in the City - Too Good To Be True...' which was published in 1987. On
the issue of the abolition of fixed commissions and single capacity dealing he
said this;
"...I immediately pointed out that there
would be very large-scale repercussions from that decision, but it was denied
from the Treasury Bench by Ministers. 'Oh No' they said ' we are only
interested in getting rid of minimum commissions, we want the separation of functions
to continue in the Stock Exchange.'...I don't think even the Council of the
Stock Exchange appreciated that if you abolished minimum commissions, it was
extremely unlikely that the separation of functions could survive, and the
reason why the separation of functions couldn't survive is that without minimum
commissions, there would not be sufficient profit to be made unless firms were
going to deal on their own account (which hitherto, they had been strictly
prohibited from so doing, because it posed a conflict of interests)...They
would have to follow the American example and start speculating on their own
account..."
Really, it is from this moment, we can begin to
observe the change of the culture of the City of London's traditional ways of
dealing and also the built-in effects that the old ways of separation of
function produced in providing a disincentive to sharp dealing on behalf of
clients.
Later, in another interview with me Sir Peter
said something that with the benefit of hindsight has proven to be very
prescient. He was talking about the new face of the City of London, the
invasion of American methods of trading and American market culture, and the
wider merging of business models and moral principles, where financial houses
traded on their own account (proprietary trading) as well as trading on behalf
of clients (dual capacity); where banks underwrote securities issues and then
traded the very shares they were underwriting; where new financial contracts,
many of them very little understood were created by one department of an institution
and traded by another, but with direct access between the two sides to the
operation. He said:
"I suspect we shall lurch from scandal to
scandal as a result of moving into dual capacity, particularly as it is to be
internationalised...Whether in the long run the general community will be well
served by having these huge new financial conglomerates, where you get (retail)
banks, merchant (Investment) banks, and foreign banks all mixed in together
with a British stockbroking firm, I very much doubt. I think it's going to be
extremely difficult to regulate, I think that the authority of the Bank of
England will be greatly undermined and I
think a great many of the people who will be operating in future (in the City
of London) will have different traditions from those in which my generation has
grown up and I think you will get a lot of scandals and when these scandals
break, the Conservative Party and the Government will be held responsible for
them..."
These words were uttered in 1986 but Sir
Peter's wisdom has proven to be exquisitely accurate, particularly with
reference to the most recent crises.
However, we have to look more closely at the
attitudes of the traders to appreciate how much their own trading culture
predicates their willingness to break the law and commit criminal acts. I
describe these people as being 'regulatorily resistant' and I will spell out my
logic in identifying this phenomenon.
Much of the trading activity which takes place
within the banking environment, particularly in the area of proprietary trading
is literally no different from gambling on horse races or games of chance and
its practitioners tend, generally, to possess the same commercial mentality as
the gambler.
At the
same time, both floor and desk market professionals tend to be heavily
influenced by a trading culture which preaches the virtues of adopting a grossed-out, high profiled,
aggressive, risk-taking personality, which needs to be constantly attested to.
Psychologically,
many of these men and women can be defined as being 'regulatorily resistant'.
Theirs is a primarily deviant, norm-evasive, criminogenic culture, not much
given to the willing acceptance of regulatory control. Such an uncompromising
statement should not be immediately interpreted to mean that these practitioners
are committing wholesale overt criminal acts. It simply means that their
risk-taking culture, itself the antithesis of the traditional perception of the
risk-reduction function of these markets; coupled with the highly competitive
environment within which they work, whose new traditions give all the
impression of flouting traditional, 'old market' norms; predispose them to
break the rules more readily than practitioners in other commercial sectors.
These are the traders to whom the compliance officer is generally seen as 'the
business prevention officer' and the traders tend to view each new regulatory
notice as an irritating inconvenience standing in the way of increasingly
innovative trading. Each new
regulatory requirement is looked upon as a challenge to the ingenuity of the
traders, and competitions are held by dealers to see who can get round the
controls undiscovered, and in the most profitable manner.
In his article, 'Mavericks at the Casino: Legal
and Ethical Indeterminacy in the Financial Markets', Christopher Stanley identified the
development of this new phenomenon of regulatory resistance within the
previously ordered environment of the City of London . He says;
"...The New City reflected the ideological
aspirations of a system of political
administrations which disrupted the post-war consensus of relations between
polity and economy. It also reflected the Casino or Disorganisation of
Capitalism: 'an international financial system in which gamblers in the casino
have got out of hand'. The New City
was international, technological and subscribed to the 'Enterprise Culture'
ethos which stressed individual success and self-reliance as the primary indicators
of excellence. The structural changes which the Government introduced, in terms
of trading practice and regulation, operated with the new financial products
and markets to ensure that the particular elite of the Old City, which was
perceived as a dangerously destabilising hegemonic counterforce as a result of
the tension between Establishment and Disestablishment, was dislodged in the
face of externally imposed change. Thus settled norms of conduct were open to
disruption'.
Pursuing the 'Legitimation of Deviancy' theory,
Stanley drew
upon the concepts of the 'Anomie of Affluence' (on which topic I have blogged
previously) to attempt 'explanations in this formulation of individual conduct
within this particular field of moral and economic deregulation.' He posited a vision of a market in which
money no longer possessed any intrinsic value as a benchmark of the underlying value of the commodity traded, but
became a 'free-floating signifier detached from the real processes to which it
once referred...there is therefore a transition in its nature as a commodity to
which moral or ethical values can be attached. In addition the artificiality of
electronic money enabled the further disappearance of the victim and the
possibility of justification through reference to prevailing economic
rationality, ie 'Greed is Good'.
Thus, no matter how much money these people
were paid in salaries or bonuses, it was never enough and the figures needed to
be increased constantly in order to provide any sense of value or self-worth.
The bonus payment became a justifier of their actions, regardless of their criminogenic
potential.
This specific problem of ‘regulatory
resistance’ or if you like, 'moral
delinquancy', has been endemic in the regulatory model of the UK’s financial
sector since the passing of the Financial Services Act 1986. In this blog, one
of my areas of focus is to attempt to expand and develop the concept of the
‘criminogenic’ nature of the state of regulatory resistance, or ‘legitimised
deviancy’ which so many financial practitioners espouse. This is what is meant
by the phrase that you cannot impose moral standards on people who don't wish
to be moral. By ‘criminogenic’ I mean conduct or behavior which has the
potential to become criminal, or at least, so vitally damaging at some stage in
the process, that any attempts to deal with the problem will almost inevitably
lead to further potential criminal behaviour.
By examining the behaviour and conduct of
persons within the financial sector, we can establish traits which indicate a
potential to be more or less willing to engage in conduct or behavior which may
result in the commission of criminogenic activity. Alternatively, where,
through ignorance of the underlying criminogenic potential of new products or
sales practices, those employed to ‘apply compliance procedures’ in the market
ignore the likelihood of the new risks being generated. In so doing, they allow
the damaging conduct to continue, and in examining this conduct, we can begin
to determine where they are exposing the market to far greater systemic risk
than it either needs or can cope with.
.A derivatives trader who habitually spends his
evenings spending vast amounts of his firm’s money entertaining clients in
lap-dancing clubs, the kind of man who is willing to pay the bill for confirmed
criminal offences, ie hiring prostitutes
(supplying prostitution) and supplying recreational narcotics, is not the kind of man who is going to spend
too long worrying about the finer niceties of the Insider Dealing rules, the money
laundering regulations, or the way in which he trades LIBOR!
‘As long as we got results, as long as we got
our commission and good feedback from the clients, they (the employing bank)
didn’t really give a shit…I think the banks know the situation, and so they
don’t do the random drug tests, because they know half their staff would be on
it, and they know that in a high-pressure job, they have to allow their traders
to have these excesses. They don’t care about the health of their workforce as
long as they’re making money…’ (Seth Freedman)
‘ …prompted by the beckoning finger from the
clearly coked-up Asian chick nearest the open door, I nervously walked towards
the car. I clumsily shuffled into my seat and saw in the gloom my three
colleagues all sitting with their respective new lady-friends. They were all
snorting yet more lines of cocaine that our ever-so-thoughtful hosts had
prepared for us on little mirrors…’ (Geraint Anderson)
The basis of the underlying theory is a concept
which is well-known to any experienced street detective who is trained to deal
with crime and to recognize the signs of the criminogenic personality, and briefly put, states that those who act or behave in an anomic fashion in their
ordinary, every-day existence, who bend or break minor rules or simple laws for
their own self-gratification, or who refuse to conform to ordinary norms of
human conduct at times when their surrounding conditions would require such
behavior, will have a greater propensity
to act in a similar, anomic way in many other circumstances, and where a
situation arises which gives them a series of choices, they will inevitably take the line of least
resistance.
The American criminologist James Q Wilson has
alluded to this kind of ‘behavioural arbitrage’ when defining his “broken
windows” theory of criminal conduct. Those who are prepared to commit minor
acts of criminal activity as a matter of course, have little difficulty in
committing more serious acts of criminality when occasion demands.
These phenomena are familiar to criminologists
because we have been trained in their understanding and we have experienced
their reality, which is why you will read my consistent demands for a greater
degree of criminalisation for these actors, because as potential criminals,
they have to be treated like criminals because it is the only sanction they
fear and understand..
Unfortunately, our skills and our experiences
are routinely denied and ignored by financial practitioners and financial
regulators, all of whom believe that they know better, and think that they can
regulate financial markets by simply denying that there is the potential for
financial criminals to commit financial crimes. It has been ever thus, and will
continue in the same vein, and when the next major financial scandal erupts, as
it will as surely as the night follows the day, the Great and the Good will
still be asking themselves why no-one has been prosecuted, and why no bankers
have gone to prison, and Sir Peter Tapsell's wise words will prove themselves
to be even more perspicacious than before.
Listening to John Cameron giving evidence to
the Banking Commission, I found it quite sad when he said, rather wistfully; 'You
can't impose moral standards on people who don't wish to be moral': If the
banks and the regulators employed people who understand how and why this
situation exists, perhaps he wouldn't have needed to make that observation!
5 comments:
This is a genuinely fascinating history lesson. I would never have guessed the rot began with shortsighted labour tinkerings.
The psychology rings true as well -- although it’s clearly not just “refusal to conform”, it’s based on a sense of outright superiority vis-à-vis rules, very much as in the Bonfire of the Vanities’ “Masters of the Universe” attitude -- “There was no limit!”
Hattersley or no, I think this was likely to begin sooner or later. Human beings almost never take the advice of Laozi to live as cautiously as a fox crossing the ice. Once a period of safety has settled in overconfidence tends to be next. Many civilisations with major futures trading components, since Babylon, are bankrupted by them at some point.
I’d love to see the faces if fixed rates returned!
Hi Rowan, Is there a way to get in contact with you - email? Mine is ileneca@gmail.com. I'm wondering if you allow reposts with links of some material in your blog. Thanks, Ilene
So happy to support your organization.
כספות
Thanks for sharing, this is a fantastic post.Thanks Again. Fantastic.
כספות
Come and see how 1,000's of people like YOU are working for a LIVING by staying home and are living their dreams TODAY.
CLICK HERE TO START IMMEDIATELY
Post a Comment