"...Go where you will, in business parts, or
meet who you like of businessmen, it is - and has been for the last three years
- the same story and the same lament. Dishonesty, untruth, and what may, in
plain English, be termed mercantile swindling within the limits of the law,
exists on all sides and on every quarter…"
No, this is
not a comment from a contemporary website, it is taken from an editorial published
in Temple Bar Magazine, of 1866. It was written when
England was experiencing a plethora of fraudulent offerings in Railway shares,
but the tenor of its complaint is as relevant today as it was then!
There is a
growing groundswell of informed opinion among modern commentators that
financial regulators should be far more willing to bring criminal charges
against those financial practitioners whose actions should be construed as more
than just negligent or incompetent.
I have never
understood why white collar criminals should be treated in a different manner
from working class criminals, but the fact remains that they are treated
differently, and have been for many, many years.
The
phenomenon was first recorded in a paper entitled 'White Collar Crime',
published in 1949 by the American criminologist Edwin Sutherland, in which he
pointed out;
"...‘There is a consistent bias involved in
the administration of criminal justice under laws which apply to business and
the professions and which therefore involve only the upper socio-economic group..."
In 'White Collar Crime', Sutherland argued that the
behaviour of persons of respectability, from the upper socio-economic class,
frequently exhibits all the essential attributes of crime, but that it is only
rarely dealt with as such. This situation arose, he said, from a tendency for
systems of criminal justice in Western societies to favour certain economically
and politically powerful groups and to disfavour others, notably the poor and
unskilled who comprise the bulk of the visible criminal population.
"...Probably much more important however, is
the cultural homogeneity of legislators, judges and administrators with
businessmen. Legislators admire and respect businessmen and cannot conceive of
them as 'criminals’; businessmen do not conform to the popular stereotype of
the 'criminal..."
Another American sociologist William Chambliss put it
this way;
"...One of the reasons we fail to understand
business crime is because we put crime into a category that is separate from
normal business. Much crime does not fit into a separate category. It is
primarily a business activity..."
In his research, Sutherland discovered that the white
collar criminal has no real fear of the regulators appointed to control the
activities of the businessman, a state of affairs which he felt impeded the
proper control of their activities. He discovered that actions by the
regulators were considered to be an unfortunate interlude, but carried very
little exclusionary status. He
identified that;
"...the violation of the laws designed to
regulate business behaviour does not necessarily mean that the violator will
lose social status among his business associates. Although some members of the industry may
think less of him, others will still admire him..."
It was very clear that the actions of regulators which
were seen as a bureaucratic part of a governmental process, were not considered
to possess a status which would diminish the perpetrator in the eyes of his
social peers. He said;
"... white collar criminals customarily
feel and express contempt for law, government and regulators in a way similar
to that in which professional thieves express contempt for policemen and
judges. Businessmen characteristically believe that the least amount of government
is the most desirable state..."
My own experiences of dealing with white-collar
criminals had demonstrated very similar findings and during some academic
research I undertook, I decided to study whether or not the finding of a guilty
verdict for a criminal offence of dishonesty would have an exclusionary impact
upon a financial practitioner.
One financial criminal had said to me rather ruefully
'...the white collar sector always assumed that its wrong-doing would be
treated somehow differently from other crimes...'
George Robb
(1992) in what is by far the most systematic discussion of nineteenth century
business crime to date notes the reluctance of the legal and criminal justice
systems to intervene in the social differentiation of the treatment of white
collar criminals. He states;
"...From
the mid-nineteenth century through the early decades of the twentieth, the law
put few obstacles in the paths of white collar criminals, trusting instead that
the free market would regulate itself and that good business would drive out
bad. The liberal outlook was taken up by the law courts which neglected
business frauds and treated white collar criminals with comparative leniency. Throughout
much of this period, cultural perceptions of 'criminality' remained focused on
the 'dangerous classes' while elite misconduct was seen as a relatively minor
social ill..."
He notes that
the harshest sentences for white collar offences were reserved for embezzling
clerks rather than leading businessmen. He adds another factor, directly
associated with the high status of the business community.
"...Another
reason frequently given for the lenient sentencing of most white-collar
criminals was that the shame and social disgrace attendant on criminal
conviction were punishment enough for middle-class persons. Exclusion from
polite society was viewed as a more serious penalty than imprisonment..... For
white collar criminals prison was seen as ancillary to their personal sense of
shame and loss of social status..."
I wanted to
test how effective the social exclusionary impact would be for a financial
practitioner being found guilty of a crime. My research set out to establish
how financial practitioners would respond to the news that one of their social
and commercial circle had first been suspected of, and then convicted for
committing offences of insider dealing (a regulatory issue in their eyes) as
opposed to an offence of theft (a criminal offence in their eyes).
In so doing I
wanted to test Sutherland's assertion that regulatory offences were considered
less important than criminal offences and would not carry the same degree of
social and commercial exclusion.
In the course
of a questionnaire which was completed by 93 financial services practitioners,
I posed the following questions.
"...A
person in another company who you have known socially for a long time and with
whom your company has done business for many years has been reported in a
serious newspaper as being suspected of Insider Dealing. How would this report
impact on your social dealings with them..?"
48% responded
that it would place a strain on their social relationship.
The question
then asked how would it affect their commercial relations with them.
49% responded
that it would place a strain on their commercial relationship.
They were then
asked how a report of the other person being suspected of theft would affect
their social dealings.
50% said it
would place a strain on their social relations.
The question
then asked how it would affect their commercial relations.
Again 50% said
it would place a strain on their commercial relationships, while 38% said it
would cause them to avoid any business dealings with them.
They were then
asked how the fact that the person had been convicted of insider dealing would
affect their social relationship.
In social
dealings 38% said it would place a strain on their social dealings while 28%
said it would cause them to avoid the social relationship. However, 18% said it
would make no social difference at all.
In business
dealings 78% said it would cause them to drop the business relationship
altogether.
Finally when
asked how a conviction for theft would affect their social dealings, 36% said it would cause them to drop social
dealings altogether, while another 30% said it would cause them to avoid them
socially.
When asked how
it would affect their commercial dealings, 92% said they would drop the
commercial relationship altogether.
It was clear
that insider dealing generally did not attract the same degree of social opprobrium
as theft. Significantly, more respondents said that in social dealings, a
report that a person was suspected of insider dealing would make no difference
to their relationship than if that person was suspected of theft. More
respondents thought that suspicion of theft would place a greater strain on
their relationship than suspicion of insider dealing.
A very similar
pattern emerged in social attitudes towards persons convicted of theft and
insider dealing. Again, insider dealing did not attract the same degree of
opprobrium and the difference between those who would avoid the social
relationship in either case and those who would drop the social relationship
was remarkably similar.
In business
dealings however the figures were dramatically different from those identified
in social dealings. Again, insider dealing generally did not attract the same
degree of opprobrium as theft, but nevertheless, the percentages of respondents
who would drop the business relationship altogether for persons convicted of
theft or insider dealing was significant.
What was very
clear from these responses was that in business dealings, conviction of a
criminal offence places the convicted person in a very defined capacity as far
as financial practitioners are concerned, which is in a marked contrast to their social position.
These figures clearly demonstrate that while financial practitioners are more prepared to tolerate breaches of the social code, borne out by the fact that a greater percentage are prepared to continue a social relationship with a convicted person, in business, the vast majority are unable to continue any relationship with a convicted person. It is felt that these figures provide support for Sutherland's theory that breaches of the business code are considered more seriously than breaches of the social code and it is submitted that the breach identified here is not so much the specific offence for which the individual is convicted but the fact of the conviction itself.
These figures clearly demonstrate that while financial practitioners are more prepared to tolerate breaches of the social code, borne out by the fact that a greater percentage are prepared to continue a social relationship with a convicted person, in business, the vast majority are unable to continue any relationship with a convicted person. It is felt that these figures provide support for Sutherland's theory that breaches of the business code are considered more seriously than breaches of the social code and it is submitted that the breach identified here is not so much the specific offence for which the individual is convicted but the fact of the conviction itself.
I believe that
these statistics prove categorically that the financial sector sees little to
fear in the actions of regulators, because whatever the outcome, the penalties
do not lead to social or commercial exclusion from the financial sector. Fines
have no impact on the individuals in the banks, instead, their impact is only
felt by the shareholders.
The
much-trumpeted theory that reputational damage is caused does not seem to have
too great a degree of preventative effect.
However, what
clearly works beyond any other measure is a conviction for what could be termed
'an ordinary criminal offence'. It immediately places the defendant in the
ranks of ordinary common criminals, and its commercial exclusionary impact has
been amply demonstrated in this article. Being convicted of a crime is the
route to the door marked 'exit', and it means that the convicted person can
never come back into the City because no-one will be willing to work with him
or employ him in future.
It must be
hoped that we will not have to listen to any more special pleading on the part
of the regulators that there are other, better methods of regulating the
financial sector, methods which have a greater deterrent effect, because there
are none!
In addition,
criminal convictions lead to asset confiscation orders, and financial recovery
proceedings, so ill-gotten gains can be recovered from the criminal. The
proceeds of the crimes become launderable and any other person who has
facilitated in their distribution or dissemination can be prosecuted for money
laundering.
For these
reasons, we must insist that Government implement an urgent review of the
powers of the regulators to bring criminal prosecutions, and their relationship
with the SFO and the Crown Prosecution Service to be upgraded and given far
more flexibility, in the hope that we shall see many more banksters being
forced to grip the rails at the Old Bailey.
A few selected
prosecutions and convictions will send such a shock-wave through the ranks of
the hitherto spoiled and arrogant financial practitioners so that they will
quickly lose the mistaken perception that they are a 'protected species'.
1 comment:
Nice one Rowan. Having spent some time looking for peer reviewed research on whether deterrence has any impact on the likelihood of criminal offending - an finding none the ONLY solution is to detect, try, convict and imprison. Given Rowan's research findings it is imperative regulators and others don't 'dick around' with simple non-compliance offences BUT go for the big hit of theft, fraud etc.
Post a Comment